Subscribe: Comments on: HEALTH REFORM: Porter And Teisberg’s Utopian Vision
Preview: Comments on: HEALTH REFORM: Porter And Teisberg’s Utopian Vision

Health Affairs BlogHEALTH REFORM: Porter And Teisberg’s Utopian Vision – Health Affairs Blog

At the intersection of health, health care, and policy.

Last Build Date: Mon, 24 Oct 2016 15:45:00 +0000


HEALTH REFORM: Porter And Teisberg’s Utopian Vision

Tue, 10 Oct 2006 14:00:23 +0000

In their recently published manifesto, Redefining Health Care (2006), Michael E. Porter and Elizabeth Olmsted Teisberg — hereafter simply PT — offer a utopian vision of a health system that might occur to anyone possessed of a modicum of common sense but not too familiar with the real world of health care. In these authors’ utopian vision — summarized in the Conclusion of their book, and also in an earlier article in the Harvard Business Review (24 June 2004) — our health system would consist of a myriad of mini health care systems, each clinically integrated around one of a myriad of clearly identifiable “medical conditions,” each of which has a standard, finite life cycle. Each of several competing health systems specializing in a particular condition would quote for its treatment a single price, covering the entire life cycle of the episode. Just how and when that price would be paid is not made clear. An individual afflicted with, say, standard medical condition no. 387 would be provided with accurate information on the price charged and the “health outcomes” achieved by the competing health systems specializing in condition no. 387. The afflicted individual would then choose the system offering the best “health outcomes” per dollar the consumer would have to pay. This market is described by the authors as a “positive sum” game in which the economic and professional incentives of all participants are aligned towards one goal only: the maximization of the “value,” defined by the authors as “the quality of patient outcomes [sic] relative to the dollars expended” (p. 98). In a recent interview in the Conference Board’s Across the Board (July/August 2006), Porter professes himself “stunned” that this vision has not driven the health policy debate before. In fact, numerous distinguished authors before PT have hit upon the central idea of their book, that “value must be measured for the patient, not the health plan, hospital doctor, or employer.” The reason why no health system anywhere in the world has yet been structured around this idea is that the real world of health care is much more complex, and solutions to its problems are much more intractable than these two authors dream in their philosophy. For starters, PT vastly underestimate how hard it will be in practice to categorize the complaints patients present to the health system neatly into a finite set of standard “medical conditions,” each with a standard life cycle. Next, they vastly underestimate how hard it will be to define, measure, and capture in user-friendly metrics the often subtle, multidimensional “health outcomes” for which the providers of health care are to be rewarded in PT’s utopian market. Who would read the meter on these metrics and report them to the public: the providers themselves, or some third party? If providers, who would audit the data for accuracy, and what penalties would there be for gaming the numbers? Furthermore, these “health outcomes” are driven by many environmental, socioeconomic, and behavioral factors completely outside the health system’s control. Absent proper statistical control for these other factors in the published metrics, the mini health systems in PT’s world surely would be tempted to control for these factors operationally, by discriminating against certain patients thought to be associated with infelicitous external factors — e.g., race or educational attainment. It would allow them to report better “value” along PT’s definition. The Reality Of Health Policymaking Finally, and most importantly, PT seem totally innocent of the often cynical modus operandi by which modern democracies make health policy. To illustrate with just one example, in the early 1990s the Physician Payment Review Commission (PPRC), which advised Congress on paying physicians for services rendered Medicare beneficiaries, had proposed to bundle the services of radiologists, anesthesiologists, and pathologists (the RAPs) into the per case fees Medicare[...]